Civil Society
- Type of paper Critical Thinking
- Subject Political Science
- Number of pages 5
- Format of citation MLA
- Number of cited resources 4
- Type of service Writing
select one prompt from the list below to address in a 4 – 6 double spaced paper: 1. What is the relationship between the ″two faces of culture″, identified by David Laitin? How are both classified and how does one ″face″ compensate for the other? Which one do you think is more critical to our understanding of political culture, or do you think both are equally inter-dependent? In addressing this question, make sure you provide at least one example to explain your rationales. They may be taken from class, or they can be something you′re familiar with. The goal here is to demonstrate your critical thinking skills regarding these two facets. 2. Taken directly from one of the discussion questions, but with the ability to expand a lot more utilizing Putnam, Sabetti, and Berman: Do you feel that democratic potential today is largely conditioned by the past? In other words, is the amount of democratic potential in a country, a region, or a region of a country, basically predetermined by a series of events in the distant past that present individuals basically have no control over? And if this is so, is there any hope that certain regions of the world can “escape” their past and actually develop into something better? 3. Does culture shape institutions, or do institutions shape culture? You can use elements from either our discussion of theories of social capital, or begin your foray into theories of social character.
World Politics 49.3 (1997) 401-429
Civil Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic Sheri Berman
*Note: Please note the [End of Page X] inserts. These designate the original page numbers for the article published in World Politics. If you are going to cite parts of this article for any of your papers, please note the original page numbers indicated for your footnotes.
Practically everywhere one looks, from social science monographs to political speeches to People
magazine, the concept of “civil society” is in vogue. A flourishing civil society is considered to have helped
bring down the Evil Empire and is held to be a prerequisite for the success of post-Soviet democratic
experiments; a civil society in decline is said to threaten democracy in America. Tocqueville is the theorist
of the decade, having noted a century and a half ago that “Americans of all ages, all stations in life, and
all types of disposition are forever forming associations.” Further, he linked such behavior to the
robustness of the nation’s representative institutions. “Nothing,” he claimed, “more deserves attention
than the intellectual and moral associations in America. . . . In democratic countries the knowledge of how
to combine is the mother of all other forms of knowledge; on its progress depends that of all the others.” 1
Today neo-Tocquevilleans such as Robert Putnam argue that civil society is crucial to “making
democracy work,” 2 while authors like Francis Fukuyama and Benjamin Barber (who differ on everything
else) agree that it plays a key role in driving political, social, and even economic outcomes. 3 This new
conventional wisdom, however, is flawed. It is simply not always true that, as Putnam (for example) puts
it, “Tocqueville was right: Democratic government is strengthened, not [End Page 401] weakened, when it faces a vigorous civil society.” 4 This essay will show how a robust civil society actually helped scuttle
the twentieth century’s most critical democratic experiment, Weimar Germany.
Associational life flourished in Germany throughout the nineteenth and early in the twentieth century. Yet
in contrast to what neo-Tocquevillean theories would predict, high levels of associationism, absent strong
and responsive national government and political parties, served to fragment rather than unite German
society. It was weak political institutionalization rather than a weak civil society that was Germany’s main
problem during the Wilhelmine and Weimar eras. As Samuel Huntington noted almost three decades ago,
societies with highly active and mobilized publics and low levels of political institutionalization often
degenerate into instability, disorder, and even violence; 5 German political development provides a classic
example of this dynamic in action. During the interwar period in particular, Germans threw themselves
into their clubs, voluntary associations, and professional organizations out of frustration with the failures
of the national government and political parties, thereby helping to undermine the Weimar Republic and
facilitate Hitler’s rise to power. In addition, Weimar’s rich associational life provided a critical training
ground for eventual Nazi cadres and a base from which the National Socialist German Workers’ Party
(NSDAP) could launch its Machtergreifung (siezure of power). Had German civil society been weaker, the
Nazis would never have been able to capture so many citizens for their cause or eviscerate their
opponents so swiftly.
A striking implication of this analysis is that a flourishing civil society does not necessarily bode well for
the prospects of liberal democracy. For civil society to have the beneficial effects neo-Tocquevilleans
posit, the political context has to be right: absent strong and responsive political institutions, an
increasingly active civil society may serve to undermine, rather than strengthen, a political regime.
Political institutionalization, in other words, may be less chic a topic these days than civil society, but it is
logically prior and historically more important. As Huntington put it, a well-ordered civic polity requires “a
recognizable and stable pattern of institutional authority . . . political institutions [must be] sufficiently
strong to provide the basis of a legitimate political order and working political community.” Without such
political institutions, societies will lack trust and the ability to define and realize [End Page 402] their common interests. 6 Political scientists need to remember that Tocqueville himself considered Americans’
political associations to be as important as their nonpolitical ones, and they need to examine more closely
how the two interact in different situations. 7
Neo-Tocquevillean Theories
The logic of neo-Tocquevillean theories bears closer examination. Contemporary scholars, it turns out,
are not the first to “rediscover” the great Frenchman, nor even the first to link group bowling and political
development. 8 After World War II several social scientists also claimed to have found in associational life
a key to understanding democracy’s success or failure.
During the 1950s and 1960s social scientists such as William Kornhauser and Hannah Arendt helped turn
the concept of “mass society” into a powerful theory for explaining the disintegration of democracy and
the rise of totalitarianism in Europe. 9 This school believed that Europe’s slide into barbarism was greased
by, among other factors, the collapse of intermediate associations across much of the Continent during
the interwar years; the epigraph to Kornhauser’s Politics of Mass Society was Tocqueville’s warning that
“if men are to remain civilized or to become so, the art of associating together must grow and improve in
the same ratio in which the equality of conditions is increased.” 10 [End Page 403] Drawing on Durkheim, and to a lesser degree on Marx, the mass society theorists argued that industrialization and modernity
estranged citizens from one another, leaving them rootless and searching for ways of belonging. Ripped
from their traditional moorings, masses were available for mobilization by extremist movements–unless,
that is, individuals could develop communal bonds through organizational affiliations and involvement.
Without “a multiplicity of independent and often conflicting forms of association,” Kornhauser wrote,
“people lack the resources to restrain their own behavior as well as that of others. Social atomization
engenders strong feelings of alienation and anxiety, and therefore the disposition to engage in extreme
behavior to escape from these tensions.” 11
Civil society, according to these theorists, was an antidote to the political viruses that afflicted mass
society. Participation in organizations not only helped bring citizens together, bridging cleavages and
fostering skills necessary for democratic governance, but it also satisfied their need to belong to some
larger grouping. According to this view, a key reason for the collapse of the Weimar Republic was its
status as a classic mass society, which made it susceptible to the blandishments of totalitarian
demagoguery. Hitler’s supporters were drawn primarily from alienated individuals who lacked a wide
range of associational memberships and saw in the NSDAP a way of integrating themselves into a larger
community; had German civil society been stronger, the republic might not have fallen. 12
The empirical evidence did not support such a causal sequence. For this and other reasons (such as the
advent of newer and trendier theories), by the late 1960s social scientists had moved on and the concept
of mass society had fallen out of vogue. Beginning in the 1970s, however, a third wave of democratization
swept across the globe, 13 and scholars sought to identify its causes, as well as those factors that
determined democratic success more generally. Several were drawn to the same Tocquevillean insights
that had attracted Kornhauser, Arendt and others a few decades earlier. Putnam’s Making Democracy
Work was particularly [End Page 404] important for the revival of interest in the role played by private, voluntary associations in sustaining vibrant democracy. 14
Like the mass society theorists, recent neo-Tocquevillean analyses stress the way individuals relate to
each other and their society when explaining why democratic regimes function well. To measure and
explain the success of democracy, Putnam, for example, uses the concepts of civic community and social
capital; for both of these the key indicator is what might be termed associationism, the propensity of
individuals to form and join a wide range of organizations spontaneously. According to Putnam:
Civil associations contribute to the effectiveness and stability of democratic government . . . both because of their “internal” effects on individual members and because of their “external” effects on the wider polity. Internally, associations instill in their members habits of cooperation, solidarity, and public spiritedness. . . . Externally . . . a dense network of secondary associations . . . [enhances the articulation and aggregation of interests and] contributes to effective social collaboration. 15
Associations “broaden the participants’ sense of self, developing the ‘I’ into the ‘We.'” “Networks of civic
engagement,” meanwhile, “foster sturdy norms of generalized reciprocity and encourage the emergence
of social trust,” which help resolve dilemmas of collective action and smooth economic and political
negotiations. 16 For Putnam almost any type of secondary association will serve these functions, as long
as it is not organized around vertical bonds of authority and dependency. As he puts it: “The manifest
purpose of the association [need not] be political.” 17 “Taking part in a choral society or a bird-watching
club can teach self-discipline and an appreciation for the joys of successful collaboration,” he writes, thus
contributing to the efficiency of regional government in Italy; the decline of league bowling, similarly,
signals the decay of democracy in the United States. 18 In sum, for Putnam and others [End Page 405] in the new generation of neo-Tocquevillean analysts, associationism is both an indicator of healthy
democracy and a prerequisite for it.
Testing the Theory
This neo-Tocquevillean thesis has attracted much attention, especially in its application to the
contemporary American scene. Nevertheless, there has actually been little in-depth analysis by political
scientists of the “internal” and “external” effects associations actually have on individual members and the
wider polity. 19 This essay therefore sets out to test the claims of the theory–specifically, by probing the
effects of associationism on the political life of one country (Germany) over the course of almost a century
(from the mid-1800s to the Nazi takeover in 1933). The investigation is facilitated by the work of historians
of Germany, who, largely unnoticed by political scientists, have fought their own battles over some related
issues: those debates provide extensive evidence of the vigor of German civil society, along with
documentation of its causes and effects.
One might counter, of course, that a theory based on only a single case is inherently problematic and
that, moreover, 20 German political development during this period was certainly influenced by a range of
factors extending beyond civil society, many of them highly particular. Nevertheless, there are several
reasons why an inability of neo-Tocquevillean analysis to account for the central features of this case
should be significant and troubling. First, scholars have long viewed the Weimar Republic and its collapse
as a crucial theoretical testing ground. The disintegration of democracy in interwar Germany is so central
to our understanding of comparative politics and so critical for the history of modern Europe that we
should at the least be wary of any theory of political development that cannot explain it. Second, the [End Page 406] postwar neo-Tocquevilleans highlighted precisely this case as an example of the impact of associationism (or lack thereof) on political outcomes. And third, while the United States has been
considered the homeland of associationism ever since Tocqueville, comparable honors could also be
bestowed on Germany, making it resemble a most likely case for determining the reliability of the neo-
Tocquevillean theory.
The extraordinarily vigorous associational life of Wilhelmine and Weimar Germany was frequently
commented on, so much so in fact that contemporaries spoke of the Vereinsmeierei (roughly,
associational fetishism or mania) that beset German society and joked that whenever three or more
Germans gathered, they were likely to draw up by-laws and found an association. 21 The German passion
for forming organizations was so characteristic that it became the butt of several well-known satires,
including Kurt Tucholsky’s classic poem “Das Mitglied” (The Member). 22 Max Weber, Germany’s most
perceptive analyst during this period, took note of his countrymen’s predilection for voluntarily joining
together in groups; recognizing the significance of this phenomenon for political development, he urged
his colleagues to study German organizational life in all of its manifestations, “starting with the bowling
club [!] . . . and continuing to the political party or the religious, artistic or literary sect.” Yet Weber also
observed that German associationism, unlike its American or British counterparts, did not lead directly to
responsible citizenship, much less to liberal or democratic values. “The quantitative spread of
organizational life,” he argued, “does not always go hand in hand with its qualitative significance.” He
explicitly noted that participation in, say, a choral society did not necessarily promote true civic virtue: “A
man who is accustomed to use his larynx in voicing powerful sentiments on a daily basis without,
however, finding any connection to his actions,” he said of singing group members, “that is a man who . . .
easily becomes a ‘good citizen’ in the passive sense of the word.” 23 [End Page 407]
This essay now proceeds to explore the internal and external effects of German associationism, focusing
on the Protestant middle classes in particular because of the critical role they played in the disintegration
of the Weimar Republic and the rise of the Nazis. 24 The results show that the postwar neo-
Tocquevilleans were wrong in their assertion that an absence of civil society paved the way for the
collapse of democracy and the rise of totalitarianism in Germany. I find, to the contrary, that participation
in organizations of civil society did link individuals together and help mobilize them for political
participation (just as current neo-Tocquevillean scholars claim), but in the German case this served not to
strengthen democracy but to weaken it. And finally, I show that the NSDAP rose to power, not by
attracting alienated, apolitical Germans, but rather by recruiting highly activist individuals and then
exploiting their skills and associational affiliations to expand the party’s appeal and consolidate its position
as the largest political force in Germany. The essay concludes by probing the broader implications of the
German case for theories of political development.
Civil Society in Bismarckian and Wilhelmine Germany
German associational life grew rapidly during the late eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. Spurred by
changes in the legal code, the breakdown of preindustrial corporate traditions, and growing social wealth
and diversification, an increasingly dense network of private voluntary associations spread throughout the
country. This trend was pronounced enough for many to comment that Germany was in the grips of an
“associational passion” on the eve of the 1848 revolutions. Voluntary associations were active in public
life, in areas ranging from education to land preservation policy; in particular, they helped a growing and
self-assertive bourgeoisie pursue its social and economic interests. Many historians, therefore, have
interpreted German associational life from the mid-eighteenth to the mid-nineteenth century as a
“symptom of [End Page 408] the rise of bourgeois society and . . . a factor serving to accelerate” its development. 25
The next spurt of German associational growth began in the 1870s. One contributing factor was the
constitution adopted by the new German Reich in 1871: the granting of universal suffrage encouraged a
wide variety of groups to form organizations in order to give themselves a voice in the political sphere.
More importantly, just as the institutional structure of the Reich was prompting certain kinds of
organizational activity, the prolonged economic downturn that began in the late 1870s highlighted the
vulnerability of different groups and increased demands for state aid. During the following two decades
almost all sectors of German society engaged in a frenzy of associational activity, with heavy industry,
small business, the Mittelstand, and white-collar groups all forming their own organizations. 26 The fight
over protectionism was certainly a key reason for the emergence of new associations, but the Great
Depression, as contemporaries referred to it, did more than merely highlight the divergent interests of
different socioeconomic groups. It led many to recognize that Germany was at a historical turning point,
poised between a traditional agricultural existence and industrialized modernity. The tension between
these two visions stimulated the formation of a wide variety of organizations, many of which (such as
patriotic societies, sports and reading clubs, and neighborhood associations) were designed to foster
certain values and lifestyles, rather than directly engage the political process.
In practice, the political system set up in 1871 only widened the existing cleavages within German
society, since political parties were [End Page 409] organized around discrete, particularistic social groups and since national political structures were not strong or responsive enough to overcome social
divisions. Under these conditions, associational activity occurred largely within each sector of society and
helped lock in the fragmentation of the Reich.
These developments continued apace as the power bloc that had dominated the Reich since 1871 fell
apart and German politics entered a new phase. Bismarck had been able to hold together a majority
coalition based on antisocialism and a protectionist logroll serving the interests of “iron and rye.” By the
early 1890s, however, the Iron Chancellor had been dismissed and mounting contradictions within the
dominant classes (industry versus agriculture, protectionists versus free traders, exporters versus
producers for the domestic market) threatened to rip apart the ruling coalition. The lower and middle
classes, moreover, were becoming increasingly mobilized: electoral participation increased from 50.7
percent of those eligible in 1871 to 77.2 percent in 1887, and participation in Reichstag elections
averaged more than 75 percent from then until the outbreak of war in 1914. 27 This posed a challenge to
traditional political structures in general and to existing political parties such as the National Liberals in
particular. 28
Liberals had been the dominant force in Germany in the years after unification, but their political
organizations, like those of other established groups, found it difficult to adapt to the changing
environment in which they had to operate. Until the 1890s most parties (with the exception of the Social
Democratic Party of Germany [the SPD] and to a lesser extent the Catholic Zentrum) were informal
collections of notables (Honoratioren). These parties had little in the way of formal organization,
especially at the grassroots level, and were really active only at election time; their institutional structures
were simply not up to the task of performing well in the hurly-burly that was now German politics. 29 The
failure of the National Liberals in particular to adjust to the new conditions left many of their potential
constituents, particularly in rural areas and among sections of the middle class, searching for other ways
of expressing their social and political aspirations. This [End Page 410] helped spur yet another burst of associational growth in Germany, as organizations designed to appeal to a wide variety of disaffected
groups sprang up across the country.
By the end of the nineteenth century, therefore, a distinct and troubling pattern had already begun to
appear in Germany–the growth of civic associations during periods of strain. When national political
institutions and structures proved either unwilling or unable to address their citizens’ needs, many
Germans turned away from them and found succor and support in the institutions of civil society instead.
Because weak national political institutions reinforced social cleavages instead of helping to narrow them,
moreover, associational activity generally occurred within rather than across group lines. Under these
circumstances, associational life served not to integrate citizens into the political system, as neo-
Tocquevilleans would predict, but rather to divide them further or mobilize them outside–and often
against–the existing political regime.
As the liberal parties stumbled, their natural constituencies were left unorganized, and many of their
natural activists found themselves adrift and in search of alternative ways of becoming involved in public
affairs. As one observer has noted, “Members of the middle strata may have looked with disdain on
parties and elections, but they participated with extraordinary vigor in a dense network of other institutions
through which they sought political influence, social identity and economic advantage.” 30 Many of these
activists played critical roles in forming and staffing the nationalist associations that became so popular in
Germany in the decades before World War I.
The nationalist associations, as Geoff Eley argues, are best viewed as “symptoms and agencies of
change. They were formed as distinctive organizations within a space which the difficulties and
obsolescence of an older mode of dominant-class politics had opened up.” 31 They targeted a broad
swath of German society and attempted to provide new channels for participation in public life. Many of
these groups were not directly “political” organizations, however. Their primary goal was not to participate
in the Wilhelmine political system, and indeed, they often defined themselves in direct repudiation of
existing political institutions and structures, arguing that they were Volksvereine (people’s associations)
devoted to cross-class solidarity and national unity. Another distinctive characteristic of these groups was
that, in contrast to old-style [End Page 411] Honoratioren organizations and parties, they placed the idea of popular legitimacy front and center. The Navy League and Pan-German League, for example, broke
new ground in terms of mass participation and activism. Both emphasized membership involvement in
discussion and decision making, and both were more willing than the Honoratioren organizations to offer
“particularly deserving” individuals the opportunity to rise to leadership positions. In many ways, the
nationalist organizations conform to the type of civil society institutions neo-Tocquevillean scholars hold
up as exemplary: “horizontally” organized, stressing equality and community, devoted to overcoming
narrow particularistic interests.
Even though increasing numbers of Germans turned away from national politics during the Wilhelmine
era, this hardly meant that they were becoming apolitical. Quite the contrary, in fact: the population was
increasingly mobilized and politically active. Some observers failed to note the change, however, because
the popular energies of the Protestant middle classes in particular were channeled into arenas outside of
national political structures and organizations. 32 Some took refuge in local government, for example, an
arena in which liberals and the middle classes more generally felt they could play an important role. A
National Liberal parliamentarian and former mayor of Berlin named Arthur Hobrecht captured this feeling
in his observation that “the citizenship which is derived from common endeavors in the organs of local
government becomes increasingly valuable for us the more the conflict of material interests fragments
contemporary society as a whole.” 33 In general, though, the discontented middle and rural strata of the
German population turned to the organizations of civil society. Some of these were drawn into political life
and developed ties with existing political parties; most however viewed themselves as a sanctuary from
traditional politics. The “various organizations to which members of the Protestant middle strata belonged,
therefore, helped to deepen [End Page 412] the divisions within their ranks and furthered the debilitating fragmentation of liberalism’s social base.” 34
On the eve of World War I, practically all Germans were discontented with national political life. The then
chancellor Bethmann-Hollweg would later write of this period:
While the storm-clouds gathered ever more heavily on the world horizon, an almost inexplicable pressure weighed on the political life of Germany. . . . [M]alaise and dejection imparted a depressing tone to political party activity, which lacked any progressive impulse. The word Reichsverdrossenheit [dissatisfaction with the imperial state] rose up out of the darkness. 35
With the national government unresponsive to calls for economic and political change and traditional
political parties unable to adjust to the era of mass politics, civil society offered an outlet for the demands
and aspirations of an increasingly restive German populace. This growth of associations during these
years did not signal a growth in liberal values or democratic political structures; instead, it reflected and
furthered the fragmentation of German political life and the delegitimization of national political
institutions. State-society relations thus took an ominous turn during the Wilhelmine era, with
consequences that would plague the Weimar Republic in later decades.
Civil Society in the Weimar Republic
The democratization of Germany at the end of World War I opened up a new phase in the country’s
associational life. Hitherto unrepresented and unorganized groups began to form their own organizations,
and the Weimar years witnessed feverish associational activity at practically every level. The number of
local voluntary associations grew throughout the 1920s, reaching extremely high levels as measured by
both historical and comparative standards. 36 National associations also [End Page 413] grew rapidly, and participation in professional organizations reached very high levels among the middle classes in
particular. 37 Yet, as in Wilhelmine Germany, the rise in associationism signaled, not the spread of liberal
values or the development of healthy democratic political institutions, but rather the reverse. The parties
of the bourgeois middle had reconstituted themselves after the war and proclaimed their commitment to
becoming true “people’s parties” and reintegrating German society. But these parties found it increasingly
difficult to hold on to their constituencies in the face of growing economic, political, and social conflicts
during the 1920s. Once again this created a vicious circle. The weakness of the bourgeois parties and
national political structures drove many citizens looking for succor and support into civil society
organizations, which were organized primarily along group lines rather than across them. The vigor of
associational life, in turn, served to further undermine and delegitimize the republic’s political structures.
The result was a highly organized but vertically fragmented and discontented society that proved to be
fertile ground for the Nazi’s rise and eventual Machtergreifung.
The German revolution raised hope among the middle classes that the “divisive” and “unrepresentative”
parties of the Wilhelmine era would be replaced by a single Volkspartei capable of unifying the nation’s
patriotic bourgeoisie and confronting the menace of social democracy. Popular support for such a course
was strong, but institutional jealousies and elite divisions prevented its adoption. Instead, Weimar’s early
years saw, along with a strengthened conservative movement, the formation of two main liberal parties
(the German Democratic Party [DDP] and the German People’s Party [DVP]) and of several smaller
regional parties, as well as reconsolidation of the Catholic Zentrum. The nonsocialist portion of Germany’s
political spectrum was thus permanently divided among a large (and eventually increasing) number of
parties, which soon began to squabble among themselves. 38
The failure of the bourgeois parties to form a single movement or even to agree on important issues of
the day did not dull the desire of the German middle classes for some form of antisocialist unity and a
[End Page 414] greater role in the political, social, and economic life of the republic. Throughout the 1920s “burghers from all social stations [continued] to demand more effective representation and a more
direct political voice” and refused to abandon the ideals of bourgeois unity and community. 39 In this
context, bourgeois social life took on a renewed vigor and sense of urgency. “More voluntary associations
attracted more members and did so in a more active fashion than ever before. Just as retailers, bakers,
and commercial employees had organized into economic interest groups, so also did gymnasts,
folklorists, singers and churchgoers gather into clubs, rally new members, schedule meetings, and plan a
full assortment of conferences and tournaments.” 40
At first, this activity occurred in conjunction with, or at least parallel to, traditional party politics, since the
newly reconstituted liberal parties tried to improve their grassroots organization, cultivate broader ties,
and even achieve the status of a “people’s party.” By the middle of the decade, however, the attempt to
reshape the relationship between national political life and civil society had failed, with the Great Inflation
of 1922-23 being the turning point. Economic historians may disagree over which socioeconomic groups
suffered the most, but there is little doubt that the middle classes suffered greatly, even if the pain was
more psychological than material. 41 This was followed by the crushing stabilization of 1923-24, which hit
white-collar workers and the middle classes particularly hard. “By the end of the 1920s the economic
position of the independent middle class had deteriorated to such an extent that it was no longer possible
to distinguish it from the proletariat on the basis of income as a criterion.” 42
The economic dislocations made all groups more jealous of their socioeconomic interests and more
strident and narrow in their political demands, while making the middle classes increasingly resentful of
both workers and big business, who were seen as having a disproportionate influence over the national
government and political parties. By fighting for measures such as the eight-hour day and better wages,
the [End Page 415] SPD was considered to be serving the class interests of its core constituency above all else; the contrast between real (if limited) SPD success and the political impotence of the middle
classes generated further paroxysms of antisocialist fervor. 43
Middle-class groups also became increasingly frustrated with the unwillingness or inability of liberal and
conservative parties such as the DDP, DVP and DNVP (German National People’s Party) to recognize
their needs and act as their representatives on the national political stage. These parties came to be seen
as the tools of big capitalists and financial interests, and the ideal of the people’s party faded as the
traditional parties of the middle and right seemed to be run by and for an unrepresentative elite. 44 Local-
level organizations and associational affiliations, furthermore, were allowed to languish or break away.
Not surprisingly, the vote share of the traditional bourgeois parties dropped precipitously throughout the
1920s. In 1924 the DVP and DDP together managed to attract only about 15 percent, and splinter parties
were forming to capture their increasingly alienated and fragmented constituency. By 1928–the high point
of economic stabilization and supposedly the “golden age” of the Weimar Republic–the splinter parties
were outpolling the traditional parties of the middle. 45
As before, middle-class tension and frustration sparked a growth in associational activity. During the
1920s middle-class Germans threw themselves into their clubs, community groups, and patriotic
organizations while increasingly abandoning the seemingly ineffectual liberal parties. By the middle of the
decade both the style and the substance of bourgeois social life in Germany had begun to change: [End Page 416]
Spurred by growing political tensions, social organizations helped to lead an unprecedented surge of apoliticism that escaped the control of bourgeois elites. . . . [M]any spokesman for Weimar apoliticism argued that social organizations would do more than cushion political strife–they would bind together a moralistic, antisocialist, “folk community” of disparate classes and strata. . . . [T]he middle and late 1920s . . . thus saw not only an acceleration of tensions that had originated in the Empire but also an unprecedented rupture between the social and the political authority of the local bourgeoisie. 46
What occurred in Germany was no less than an inversion of neo-Tocquevillean theory; not only did
participation in civil society organizations fail to contribute to republican virtue, but it in fact subverted it.
“[A]s the middle class became more and more disenchanted with and hostile towards the republic, their
energies ceased to be channeled into proto political organizations and party political organizations of the
center and right which the old elites had traditionally headed. Instead the radicalized troops of the middle
class deserted these organizations and their leaders.” 47
Private associations were correctly seen to offer benefits that the traditional bourgeois parties were failing
to provide, such as a sense of community and unity. While the DDP, DVP and DNVP had trouble shaking
their image as Honoratioren parties dominated by business and agricultural elites, many private
bourgeois associations brought together a relatively wide range of individuals and created a sense of
purpose that transcended socioeconomic divisions.
For many provincial burghers, associational life facilitated social contacts and friendships and muffled party differences. Repeatedly, the club was lauded for reconciling burghers. As an officer of a bourgeois choir in Hesse’s Marburg commented, in “a time of both internal and external antagonisms, it is the German song that binds together members of the folk . . .” In a similar fashion, the summer festival of Celle’s riflery club offered the mayor a happy example of unity between “burgher and civil servant.” 48
A fine example of these trends can be found in the World War I veterans organization known as the
Stahlhelm. One of the largest and most politically powerful organizations during the 1920s, the Stahlhelm
reached a peak membership of between five and six hundred thousand and played an important role in
Hindenburg’s election to the presidency. It had a relatively diverse membership, attracting support [End Page 417] from different socioeconomic groups, regions, and both the liberal and conservative camps. In addition, the organization encouraged a high level of membership participation, had a relatively
democratic internal structure, and maintained contacts with other clubs and associations. In the early
years of the republic the Stahlhelm developed ties with parties of the center-right and right, viewing such
links as the best way to ensure the success of its nationalist, antisocialist agenda. By the mid-1920s,
however, the organization was becoming disillusioned with traditional party politics and began to
emphasize a nationalist and populist communitarianism. Many burghers began to transfer their primary
political loyalties to it from center-right and right political parties, helping to eradicate these parties’
authority at the grassroots level. The nature of the organization is captured well by a 1927 manifesto,
which declared:
Stahlhelm does not want to form or become a new party. But it does want . . . for its members to acquire the possibility and the right of decisive participation in all positions of public service and popular representation, from the local community to the national government. . . . Stahlhelm opposes all efforts and conceptions that seek to divide the German people. It esteems highly the experience of old comradeship at the front and unity and wants to develop out of it a national sense of unity. . . . [I]n full recognition of the value and the vital unity among enterprise, entrepreneur, and fellow workers, Stahlhelm will not hinder an honest and decisive settlement of conflicts of interest. It demands, however, the maintenance and preservation of the transcending interest of the German community. 49
After 1928 the Stahlhelm began to lose membership and influence, in part because it allied itself more
closely with the DNVP, but mostly because it was unable to adjust to the increasing mobilization and
radicalism that was sweeping Germany during the late 1920s and early 1930s. The organization
remained tied to the memory of the wartime generation and was not very successful in attracting those
who came of age later. It had trouble operating amid the accelerating disintegration of traditional political
structures and did not manage to cultivate ties to [End Page 418] either the new bourgeois splinter parties or their constituencies. Ironically, therefore, while the Stahlhelm had played a crucial role in
infusing nationalist populism into the German political system and further weakening the traditional
bourgeois parties, it was the Nazis and not the Stahlhelm who would be the ultimate beneficiaries of
these trends. As the Great Depression spread throughout Europe, Germany found itself with weak
political institutions and a fragmented but highly organized civil society; this, not the atomized anomie of a
pure “mass society,” would prove to be the ideal setting for the rapid rise to power of a skilled totalitarian
movement.
The Rise of the NSDAP
During the 1920s the Nazi Party (the NSDAP) was stagnant–low on funds and unable to fill meeting halls
or amass a significant share of the vote. By 1926 the situation had become so dire that the party began to
move toward a major shift in strategy. Where previously the NSDAP had focused primarily on urban areas
and working-class voters, it now reoriented its appeal toward the middle classes, nonvoters, and farmers,
while proclaiming itself above the group divisions that plagued the country. Thus, as late as the 1928
elections the Nazis polled only 2.6 percent, whereas four years later they were the largest party in the
Weimar Republic. 50 What enabled the Nazis to make such spectacular inroads into the German
electorate? The depression, the weak response to it from mainstream parties, Hitler’s charisma and
political savvy–all these clearly played a role. A significant part of the answer, however, lies with
contemporary German civil society.
As voters abandoned traditional bourgeois parties during the 1920s and then grappled with the ravages of
the depression, a political vacuum opened up in German politics, a vacuum that offered the Nazis a
golden opportunity to assemble an unprecedented coalition. To this end, the NSDAP exploited its
increasingly strong position in Weimar’s [End Page 419] rich associational life. The dense networks of civic engagement provided the Nazis with cadres of activists who had the skills necessary to spread the
party’s message and increase recruitment. Those networks also served as a fifth column, allowing the
NSDAP to infiltrate and master a significant sector of bourgeois society before emerging to seize control
of Germany’s national political structures. As one scholar notes:
Path-breaking work in recent years on the rise of National Socialism has stressed the importance of local newspapers, municipal notables, and voluntary associations, and points to the buoyancy and vigor of civic traditions. Had bourgeois community life been overly disoriented and fragmented, the body of new evidence indicates, the Nazis would never have been able to marshal the resources or plug into the social networks necessary to their political success. 51
During the second half of the 1920s the Nazis concentrated on attracting bourgeois “joiners” who had
become disillusioned with traditional party politics. Like the neo-Tocquevilleans, Hitler recognized that
participation in associational life provided individuals with the kinds of leadership skills and social ties that
could be very useful in the political arena. 52 Civil society activists formed the backbone of the Nazis’
grassroots propaganda machine. The party also skillfully exploited their organizational contacts and social
expertise to gain insight into the fears and needs of particular groups and to tailor new appeals to them–
using them, in other words, as “focus groups.” The activists, finally, provided the movement with
unparalleled local organizations. In contrast to the other bourgeois parties, the Nazis were able to develop
flexible and committed local party chapters that enabled full and accurate two-way communication
between the national party and its frontline troops.
Recent research into local life in interwar Germany details the crucial role played by bourgeois “joiners” in
paving the way for the Nazi rise to power. Rudy Koshar’s excellent study of Marburg, for example, shows
that party members were an unusually activist bunch. “Before September 1930 there existed at least 46
Nazi party members with 73 cross-affiliations. For the period before 30 January 1933 overall, there were
at least 84 Nazi students and 116 nonstudent party adherents with 375 cross-affiliations to occupational
associations, sports clubs, non-party municipal electoral slates, civic associations, student fraternities
[End Page 420] and other local voluntary groups.” By January 1933 there was at least one Nazi Party member in one out of every four voluntary groups in the city. 53 The Nazi elite was even more well
connected. 54
Koshar describes the key role of civil society activists in creating a powerful and dynamic Nazi
organization in Marburg. By the time of the Nazi breakthrough in the 1930 elections, the NSDAP had
representatives in a wide range of civic associations working to spread the movement’s message, get out
the vote, and discredit political opponents. “The 1930-31 electoral victories were more lasting than
expected, because the NSDAP was gaining control over a field of social organizations wider than that
supporting bourgeois parties.” 55 The activists not only created a powerful electoral machine but also
helped the NSDAP to anchor itself in local communities in a way no other bourgeois party could match.
The Nazis used their local organization to design propaganda and political events that would mesh with
and appeal to Marburg’s particular social rhythms, making the NSDAP seem sympathetic and responsive
by contrast with elitist and out-of-touch liberals and conservatives.
[T]he party was attractive in part because of its positive image in conversations in the marketplace, local stores, university classrooms, fraternity houses, meeting halls, soccer fields, and homes. Hitler’s seemingly mysterious mass appeal could hardly have been so extensive without the unplanned propaganda of daily social life. . . . Through infiltration, the NSDAP gained moral authority over organizations in which it also established a material base. It was becoming the political hub, the focus of legitimacy and material power, that bourgeois constituencies had lacked. 56
The Nazis did not merely exploit their cadres’ preexisting associational bonds; they even deliberately
infiltrated activists into a wide range of bourgeois organizations in order to eliminate potential opponents
from positions of power within them. 57 Without the opportunity to exploit [End Page 421] Weimar’s rich associational network, in short, the Nazis would not have been able to capture important sectors of the
German electorate so quickly and efficiently.
A brief profile of the Nazi methods can be found in the case of the German peasantry. During the interwar
years peasants joined and participated in a wide range of professional, special interest, and regional
associations, a trend carried over from the Wilhelmine era. Early in the republic the peasantry tended to
vote liberal or conservative, but they like other bourgeois groups soon began to desert traditional political
parties. During the second half of the 1920s most peasants either withdrew from the national political
arena or gave their support to one of the new splinter parties; they did not disproportionately support the
extreme right. 58 As the depression bore down, however, the crisis in German agriculture became more
acute and the political situation in rural areas more volatile. Large landowners used their influence on the
DNVP and other political organizations to secure a large amount of help (including the notorious Osthilfe),
but the peasantry found itself without a powerful political champion.
Until late in the day the Nazis essentially ignored rural Germany, and the vaguely socialist aspects of the
Nazi program (such as land reform and expropriation) tended to drive farmers away. But by the end of the
1920s the NSDAP, clever and opportunistic in ways its competitors were not, noticed the political
potential of the frustration and unrest spreading across the countryside. In 1928, therefore, the party
refashioned its agricultural program, eliminating many offensive planks and focusing instead on the
particular needs and demands of rural inhabitants. 59
R. Walther Darre was the key figure in Nazi agricultural policy, and by the end of 1930 he decided that the
way to win the peasantry’s support and box out potential opponents in rural areas was to capture existing
agricultural organizations. In November 1930 an instruction [End Page 422] sheet ordered the NSDAP’s agricultural apparatus (agrarpolitische Apparat, or aA) to
penetrate into all rural affairs like a finely intertwined root system. . . . [The aA] should embed itself deeply in [all rural organizations] and seek to embrace every element of agrarian life so thoroughly that eventually nothing will be able to occur in the realm of agriculture everywhere in the Reich which we do not observe and whose basis we do not understand. Let there be no farm, no estate, no village, no cooperative, no agricultural industry, no local organization of the RLB [an agricultural organization], no rural equestrian association, etc., etc., where we have not–at the least–placed our [representatives]. 60
Darre became particularly interested in capturing the Reichslandbund (RLB), a major player in German
agrarian life that by the end of the 1920s had 5.6 million members. During the 1920s the RLB had
cooperated with a number of bourgeois parties including the DVP and DNVP. But eventually many RLB
members grew disgusted with the organization’s political vacillation and inept leadership and began to
consider the NSDAP as a potential champion for agricultural interests. During the latter part of 1930 Darre
decided that the best way to gain control over the RLB was by “conquering one position after another
from within.” 61 The aA focused first on placing supporters in lower ranks of the RLB, then on capturing
leadership positions. Like his führer, Darre recognized the value of gradualism and legalism, reasoning
that if the Nazis nibbled “away at [the RLB’s] official apparatus, then, along with this mortar, the big stones
will fall out on their own.” 62
After the NSDAP’s successes in local elections in 1931, Darre began to push harder for Nazi
appointments to the RLB leadership. He recognized that an official RLB endorsement could play an
important role in the 1932 elections. Soon he succeeded in getting a Nazi named one of the four
presidents of the RLB, and in 1932 the RLB duly endorsed the Nazis. Darre continued his attack on the
RLB from within, eliminating remaining non-Nazis from all influential positions. This pushed the RLB
increasingly into the Nazi fold, brandishing the NSDAP’s image as the champion of Germany’s
“neglected” groups while opening up new avenues for manipulation. “Instead of proving an obstacle to
Nazism in the countryside, the RLB and other agricultural organizations became convenient conveyor
belts for Nazi propaganda reaching deep into the [End Page 423] rural population. In this way the intermediate groups facilitated the rise of Nazism.” 63
The Nazis had infiltrated and captured a wide range of national and local associations by the early 1930s,
finally bridging the gap between bourgeois civil society and party politics that had plagued Germany for
half a century. From this base Hitler was able to achieve two goals that had long eluded German
politicians–the creation of an effective political machine and a true cross-class coalition. With these in
Nazi hands and bourgeois competitors eliminated, Hindenburg found it increasingly difficult to ignore
Hitler’s demands for a change of course. By the end of 1932 Schleicher had lost Hindenburg’s
confidence; 64 two days after Schleicher was forced to resign, Hitler was named chancellor. 65
Conclusions: Germany, Associationism, and Political Development
The German case reveals a distinct pattern of associationism that does not conform to the predictions of
neo-Tocquevillean theories. German civil society was rich and extensive during the nineteenth and early
twentieth centuries, and this nation of joiners should accordingly have provided fertile soil for a successful
democratic experiment. Instead, it succumbed to totalitarianism. This does not mean that civil society was
disconnected from German political development; it was, rather, connected in ways that the reigning neo-
Tocquevillean theories ignore.
The vigor of German civil society actually developed in inverse relation to the vigor and responsiveness of
national political institutions and structures. Instead of helping to reduce social cleavages, Germany’s
weak and poorly designed political institutions exacerbated them; instead of responding to the demands
of an increasingly mobilized population, the country’s political structures obstructed meaningful
participation in public life. As a result, citizens’ energies and interests were deflected into private
associational activities, which were generally [End Page 424] organized within rather than across group boundaries. The vigor of civil society activities then continued to draw public interest and involvement
away from parties and politics, further sapping their strength and significance. Eventually the Nazis seized
the opportunities afforded by such a situation, offering a unifying appeal and bold solutions to a nation in
crisis. The NSDAP drew its critical cadres precisely from among bourgeois civil society activists with few
ties to mainstream politics, and it was from the base of bourgeois civil society that the party launched its
swift Machtergreifung. In short, one cannot understand the rise of the Nazis without an appreciation of the
role played by German civil society, and one cannot understand the contours of that civil society without
reference to the country’s weak political institutionalization.
From Bismarck’s tenure onward German political parties exhibited two major weaknesses. 66 First, they
tended to focus on particular and relatively narrow socioeconomic groups. Workers, large landowners,
large industrialists, Catholics–all had political parties catering specifically to them. Instead of reconciling
the interests of different groups or creating a sense of national unity, therefore, parties reflected and
deepened the divisions within German society. Only Hitler was able to overcome this pattern, finally
creating a cross-class political coalition and uniting a majority (or at least a plurality) of Germans under a
single political umbrella. Second, Germany’s bourgeois parties in particular never adjusted fully to the era
of mass politics. Instead, they retained an elite organizational style and failed to develop strong
grassroots organizations and to cultivate strong ties to the associational lives of their constituencies. 67
The result was that large sectors of the German middle classes withdrew even further from national
political activity. In general, therefore, the party system served to aggravate the lack of political and social
cohesion that had plagued Germany since unification.
The weakness of such national political structures was a key reason that Germans threw themselves into
clubs, organizations, and interest groups during periods of strain like the 1870s and 1920s. Because the
[End Page 425] political system deepened social cleavages, however, civil society institutions often catered to members of a particular group: socialists, Catholics, and bourgeois Protestants each joined
their own choral societies and bird-watching clubs. However horizontally organized and civic minded
these associations may have been, they tended to hive their memberships off from the rest of society and
contribute to the formation of what one observer has called “ferociously jealous ‘small republics.'” 68
Germany was cleaved increasingly into distinct subcultures or communities, each of which had its own,
separate associational life. Civil society activity alone, in short, could not overcome the country’s social
divisions or provide the political cohesion that would have been necessary to weather the crises which
beset Germany beginning in 1914. For this, strong and flexible political institutions, particularly political
parties, would have been necessary.
On the eve of the Great Depression, Germany found itself in a precarious political situation–its civil
society was highly developed but segmented, and its mainstream bourgeois parties were disintegrating.
Many citizens active in secondary associations were politically frustrated and dissatisfied; when the
depression added economic and political chaos to the mix, the result was a golden opportunity for a new
political force. The Nazis stepped into the breach, reaching out to the disaffected bourgeois civil society
activists and using the country’s organizational infrastructure to make inroads into various constituencies.
The dense network of German associations enabled the NSDAP to create in a remarkably short time a
dynamic political machine and cross-class coalition unlike anything Germany had ever before seen–one
to which it soon succumbed.
The German case should make us skeptical of many aspects of neo-Tocquevillean theory. In particular,
German political development raises questions about what has by now become practically conventional
wisdom, namely, that there is a direct and positive relationship between a rich associational life and
stable democracy. Under certain circumstances, clearly the very opposite is the case: associationism and
the prospects for democratic stability can actually be inversely related. Furthermore, many of the
consequences of associationism stressed by neo-Tocquevillean scholars–providing individuals with
political and social skills, creating bonds between citizens, facilitating mobilization, decreasing barriers to
collective action–can be turned to antidemocratic [End Page 426] ends as well as to democratic ones. Perhaps, therefore, associationism should be considered a politically neutral multiplier–neither inherently
good nor inherently bad, but rather dependent for its effects on the wider political context. 69
The neo-Tocquevilleans have in fact already been criticized for their inability to predict whether civil
society activity will have negative or positive consequences for political development. Some, for example,
have taken Putnam to task for praising the long-term salutory effect of civil society activity in Northern
Italy while ignoring the fact that this selfsame activity proved to be consistent with Fascism. 70 What the
analysis presented here seems to indicate is that if we want to know when civil society activity will take on
oppositional or even antidemocratic tendencies, we need to ground our analyses in concrete
examinations of political reality. If a country’s political institutions and structures are capable of channeling
and redressing grievances and the existing political regime enjoys public support and legitimacy, then
associationism will probably buttress political stability by placing its resources and beneficial effects in the
service of the status quo. This is the pattern Tocqueville described.
If, on the contrary, political institutions and structures are weak and/or the existing political regime is
perceived to be ineffectual and illegitimate, then civil society activity may become an alternative to
politics, increasingly absorbing citizens’ energies and satisfying their basic needs. In such situations,
associationism will probably undermine political stability, by deepening cleavages, furthering
dissatisfaction, and providing rich soil for oppositional movements. Flourishing civil society activity in
these circumstances signals governmental and party failure and may bode ill for the regime’s future.
This latter pattern fits Germany in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, as we have seen, but
it may be applicable to many other cases as well, with provocative implications. The weakening of
communist regimes in Eastern Europe, for example, was hastened by a rise in civil society activity there
in the 1980s; parts of the contemporary Arab world are witnessing a remarkable growth in Islamist civil
[End Page 427] society activity that feeds on the citizenry’s frustration with the region’s unrepresentative and unresponsive authoritarian governments. In such situations civil society may not necessarily promote
liberal democracy, as the neo-Tocquevilleans would have it, but rather may simply corrode the
foundations of the current political order while providing an organizational base from which it can be
challenged. From this perspective, the fact that a militant Islamist movement, for example, provides its
supporters with religious classes, professional associations, and medical services tells us little about what
might happen should the movement ever gain power; it tells us much more about the political failure and
gloomy prospects of the nation’s existing regime.
Unfortunately, one need not look so far abroad to find examples of this pattern. The New York Times
noted in a recent report on the District of Columbia, for example, that for many of Washington’s residents
home rule “has come to mean a patronage-bloated, ineffective city payroll offering phantom services.”
The weakness and failure of Washington’s local government and political system, in turn, has spurred
both a rise in associational activity and a fragmentation of social consciousness and communal identity.
“Volunteerism [is] growing stronger in the face of the dwindling services, mismanagement and budget
shortfalls that bedevil the city,” according to one neighborhood activist. “Gradually,” says another, “people
come to feel they have to take care of themselves and not worry about the other guy.” 71 Another
observer proclaims: “Amid widespread disillusionment with government and its ability to solve the nation’s
most pervasive problems, a loosely formed social movement promoting a return to ‘civil society’ has
emerged . . . drawing a powerful and ideologically diverse group of political leaders.” 72 When
associationism and communitarian activities flourish in such a context, it would seem that there is cause,
not for celebration, but rather for deep concern about the failure of the community’s political institutions.
Finally, if neo-Tocquevilleans have misunderstood the true connections between civic and political
institutions, the policy advice they offer should be called into question. Responding to current public
dissatisfaction with the state of democracy in America, many have argued that the remedy lies in fostering
local associational life. This prescription may prove to be both misguided and counterproductive,
however. If a population increasingly perceives its government, politicians, and [End Page 428] parties to be inefficient and unresponsive, diverting public energies and interest into secondary associations may
only exacerbate the problem, fragment society, and weaken political cohesion further. American
democracy would be better served if its problems were addressed directly rather than indirectly.
Increased bird watching and league bowling, in other words, are unlikely to have positive effects unless
the nation’s political institutions are also revitalized. 73
Sheri Berman is Assistant Professor of Politics at Princeton University and the author of Ideas and Politics: Social Democracy in Interwar Europe (forthcoming).
Notes * The author would like to thank Peter Berkowitz, Nancy Bermeo, David P. Conradt, Manfred Halpern, Marcus Kreuzer, Andy Markovits, Anna Seleny, Kathryn Stoner-Weiss, Carolyn Warner, and especially Gideon Rose, for helpful comments and criticisms.
1. Alexis de Tocqueville, Democracy in America (New York: Harper and Row, 1988), 513, 517.
2. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993); see also idem, “Bowling Alone: America’s Declining Social Capital,” Journal of Democracy 6 (January 1995); idem, “The Prosperous Community,” American Prospect, no. 13 (Spring 1993); and idem, “The Strange Disappearance of Civic America,” American Prospect, no. 24 (Winter 1996).
3. Fukuyama, Trust: Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity (New York: Free Press, 1995); and Barber, Jihad vs. McWorld: How the Planet Is Both Falling Apart and Coming Together–and What This Means for Democracy (New York: NY Times Books, 1995).
4. Putnam (fn. 2, Making Democracy Work), 182.
5. Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968).
6. Ibid., 82-83, 5-25.
7. Michael W. Foley and Bob Edwards, “The Paradox of Civil Society,” Journal of Democracy 7 (July 1996); Larry Diamond, “Rethinking Civil Society: Toward Democratic Consolidation,” Journal of Democracy 5 (July 1994); Theda Skocpol, “The Tocqueville Problem: Civic Engagement in American Democracy” (Presidential address for the annual meeting of the Social Science History Association, New Orleans, October 12, 1996); and idem, “Unravelling from Above,” American Prospect, no. 25 (March-April 1996).
8. A distinction apparently belonging to Max Weber; see fn. 23 below.
9. William Kornhauser, The Politics of Mass Society (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1959); and Hannah Arendt, The Origins of Totalitarianism (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1973). See also Sigmund Neumann, Permanent Revolution (New York: Harper, 1942); Karl Mannheim, Man and Society in an Age of Reconstruction (New York: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1980); Erich Fromm, Escape from Freedom (New York: Rinehart, 1941); Edward Shils, “The Theory of Mass Society,” in Philip Olson, ed., America as a Mass Society (New York: Free Press, 1963); and E. V. Walter, “‘Mass Society’: The Late Stages of an Idea,” Social Research 31 (Winter 1964). It should be pointed out that the concept of mass society has a variety of different interpretations. Apart from the one discussed here, the most well known usage of the term is associated with José Ortega y Gasset, The Revolt of the Masses (New York: W. W. Norton, 1994), and other theories of cultural decay. For a recent discussion of this latter usage, see Neil McInnes, “Ortega and the Myth of the Mass,” National Interest (Summer 1996). For general overviews of the mass society literature, see Patrick Brantlinger, Bread and Circuses: Theories of Mass Culture as Social Decay (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983); and Salvador Giner, Mass Society (New York: Academic Press, 1976).
10. On the intellectual history of mass society theories, see Walters (fn. 9), 405; and Sandor Halebsky, Mass Society and Political Conflict: Toward a Reconstruction of Theory (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1976).
11. Kornhauser (fn. 9), 32; see also Arendt (fn. 9), 315-23. For a general review of the literature on this point, see Joseph R. Gusfield, “Mass Society and Extremist Politics,” American Sociological Review 17 (1982).
12. On mass society theories and the Weimar Republic, see the excellent essay by Bernt Hagtvet, “The Theory of Mass Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic: A Re-examination,” in Stein Larsen, Bernt Hagtvet, and Jan Petter Myklebust, eds., Who Were the Fascists? Social Roots of European Fascism (Bergen, Norway: Universitetsforlaget, 1980).
13. Samuel P. Huntington, The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1991).
14. Recent neo-Tocquevillean analyses are somewhat different in emphasis, however, from their earlier mass society counterparts. In particular, they focus–as Putnam’s title states–on what “makes democracy work,” that is, what makes some democracies healthier than others; there is no explicit discussion of the possibility of a new descent into totalitarianism. For Putnam and his counterparts, in other words, the dependent variable is the strength or effectiveness (it is unclear which) of democratic institutions, while for mass society theorists the dependent variable was the slide into totalitarianism.
15. Putnam (fn. 2, Making Democracy Work), 89-90. On social capital, see also James Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University, 1990).
16. Putnam (fn. 2, 1995), 67. See also idem, “Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America,” PS (December 1995); and idem (fn. 2, “The Prosperous Community”).
17. Putnam (fn. 2, Making Democracy Work), 90. For a separate argument on the consequences of organizations’ internal structures, see Harry Eckstein, “A Theory of Stable Democracy,” in Eckstein, Division and Cohesion in Democracy: A Study of Norway (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1966).
18. Putnam (fn. 2, Making Democracy Work), 90; idem (fn. 2, 1995), 70.
19. Putnam, for example, cites some development and economic studies to buttress his points, but much less empirical research has been carried out on associationism’s political effects, whether on citizens or societies. The old mass society literature did, however, spur sociologists to investigate some of these questions. See, for example, Nicholas Babchuk and John N. Edwards, “Voluntary Associations and the Integration Hypothesis,” Sociological Inquiry 35 (Spring 1965); David E. W. Holden, “Associations as Reference Groups: An Approach to the Problem,” Rural Sociology 30 (1965); Maurice Pinard, “Mass Society and Political Movements: A New Formulation,” American Journal of Sociology (July 1968); and also Sidney Verba, “Organizational Membership and Democratic Consensus,” Journal of Politics 27 (August 1965). Some political scientists are beginning to investigate these questions. See Dietland Stolle and Thomas Rochon, “Associations and the Creation of Social Capital,” in Kenneth Newton et al., eds., “Social Capital in Western Europe” (Manuscript, 1996); and idem, “Social Capital, Associations and American Exceptionalism,” in American Behavioral Scientist (forthcoming).
20. Gary King, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba, Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994), 209-12.
21. James J. Sheehan, German Liberalism in the Nineteenth Century (Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press, 1995), and Thomas Nipperdey, “Verein als soziale Struktur in Deutschland im späten 18. und frühen 19. Jahrhundert: Eine Fallstudie zur Modernisierung,” in Nipperdey, Gesellschaft, Kultur, Theorie: Gesammelte Aufsätze zur neueren Geschichte (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1976).
22. Kurt Tucholsky, “Das Mitglied,” in Mary Gerold-Tucholsky, ed., Zwischen Gestern und Morgen: Eine Auswahl aus seinen Schriften und Gedichten (Hamburg: Taschenbuch, 1952), 76.
23. Max Weber, “Geschäftsbericht und Diskussionsreden auf den deutschen soziologischen Tagungen,” in Weber, Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Soziologie und Sozialpolitik (Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr, 1924), 442, quoted in Rudy Koshar, Social Life, Local Politics, and Nazism: Marburg, 1880-1935 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1986), 4, emphasis added. See also Margaret Levi, “Social and Unsocial Capital: A Review Essay of Robert Putnam’s Making Democracy Work,” Politics and Society 24 (March 1996).
24. For a review of the literature on the middle classes and fascism, see Bernt Hagtvet and Reinhard Kühl, “Contemporary Approaches to Fascism: A Survey of Paradigms,” and Reinhard Kuhl, “Preconditions for the Rise and Victory of Fascism in Germany,” both in Larsen, Hagtvet, and Myklebust (fn. 12). See also Hans Lebovics, Social Conservatism and the Middle Classes in Germany, 1914-1933 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969); Hans Speier, German White Collar Workers and the Rise of Hitler (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1986); and Jürgen Kocka, Die Angestellten in der deutschen Geschichte, 1850-1980 (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1981). For reasons detailed in the text and notes below, observations about bourgeois Protestant associationism do not necessarily apply to its labor or Catholic counterparts, among others.
25. Nipperdey (fn. 21), 182; see also David Blackbourn and Geoff Eley, The Peculiarities of German History: Bourgeois Politics and Society in Nineteenth-Century Germany (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992), 194ff.; David Blackbourn, “The German Bourgeoisie: An Introduction,” in David Blackbourn and Richard J. Evans, eds., The German Bourgeoisie (London: Routledge, 1993); Jürgen Kocka, “The European Pattern and the German Case,” in Jürgen Kocka and Allan Mitchell, eds., Bourgeois Society in Nineteenth Century Europe (Oxford: Berg, 1993); Karl-Erich Born, “Der soziale und wirtschaftliche Strukturwandels Deutschlands am Ende des 19. Jahrhunderts,” in Hans-Ulrich Wehler, Moderne deutsche Sozialgeschichte (Cologne: Kiepenheuer und Witsch, 1966); and Vereinswesen und bürgerliche Gesellscaft in Deutschland, special issue of Historische Zeitschrift, ed. Otto Dann (Munich: R. Oldenburg Verlag, 1984).
26. Hans-Ulrich Wehler, “Der Aufstieg des Organisierten Kapitalismus und Interventionsstaates in Deutschland,” in Heinrich August Winkler, ed., Organisierter Kapitalismus: Voraussetzungen und Anfänge (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1974); Heinrich August Winkler, Mittelstand, Demokratie und Nationalsozialismus: Die politische Entwicklung von Handwerk und Kleinhandel in der Weimarer Republik (Cologne: Kiepenheuer und Witsch, 1972), 47ff.; Dirk Stegmann, Die Erben Bismarcks: Parteien und Verbände in der Spätphase des Wilhelminischen Deutschlands (Cologne: Kiepenheuer und Witsch, 1970); David Blackbourn, “Between Resignation and Volatility: The German Petite Bourgeoisie in the Nineteenth Century,” in Geoffrey Crossick and Heinz-Gerhard Haupt, eds., Shopkeepers and Artisans in Nineteenth Century Europe
(London: Methuen, 1984); and Jürgen Kocka, Facing Total War: German Society, 1914-1918 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1984).
27. Stanley Suval, Electoral Politics in Wilhelmine Germany (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1985), esp. chap. 2.
28. The following section draws heavily on Geoff Eley, Reshaping the German Right: Radical Nationalism and Political Change after Bismarck (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994). See also Blackbourn and Eley (fn. 25), 144-55; and Koshar (fn. 23), esp. 46ff.
29. Liberals did make some attempts to respond to the challenges of popular mobilization and the political organization of workers by the spd, but these proved unsuccessful. See Eley (fn. 28), 2; and Sheehan (fn. 21), pt. 6.
30. Sheehan (fn. 21), 236.
31. Eley (fn. 28), xix.
32. Workers and Catholics, by contrast, were efficiently organized through and by the spd and the Zentrum, respectively. In contrast to the liberal parties, both the spd and the Zentrum were able to create their own affiliated associations in most areas of social life. One consequence of this, however, was the further fragmentation of German society, as the associations affiliated with these parties were so encompassing as to create “subcultures” that hived off their members from other groups. Referring to the spd in particular, Dieter Groh has termed such behavior “negative integration”; see Groh, Negative Integration und revolutionärer Attentismus (Frankfurt: Verlag Ullstein GmbH, 1973). The literature on the socialist and Catholic subcultures in Wilhelmine and Weimar Germany is immense; good places to begin are the bibliographies in Eberhard Kolb, The Weimar Republic (London: Unwin Hyman, 1988); and Hans Mommsen, The Rise and Fall of Weimar Democracy (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1996).
33. Sheehan (fn. 21), 237.
34. Ibid., 237-38. See also Thomas Nipperdey, “Interessenverbände und Parteien in Deutschland vor dem Ersten Weltkrieg,” in Wehler (fn. 25).
35. Theobald von Bethmann-Hollweg, Betrachtungen zum Weltkrieg, vol. 1 (Berlin: R. Hubbing, 1919-21).
36. William Sheridan Allen, The Nazi Seizure of Power: The Experience of a Single German Town, 1922-1945 (New York: 1984); Peter Fritzsche, Rehearsals for Fascism: Populism and Political Mobilization in Weimar Germany (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990); and Koshar (fn. 23). For cross-national comparisions of the impact of civil society activity on democracy, see Nancy Bermeo, “Getting Mad or Going Mad? Citizens, Scarcity, and the Breakdown of Democracy in Interwar Europe” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the apsa, San Francisco, 1996); Nancy Bermeo and Phil Nord, eds., “Civil Society before Democracy” (Manuscript, Princeton University, 1996); and Dietrich Rueschemeyer, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens, Capitalist Development and Democracy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1992), esp. 113-14.
37. Kocka (fn. 26); idem, “The First World War and the ‘Mittelstand’: German Artisans and White Collar Workers,” Journal of Contemporary History 8 (January 1973); Gerald Feldman, “German Interest Group Alliances in War and Inflation, 1914-1923,” in Suzanne Berger, ed., Organizing Interests in Western Europe: Pluralism, Corporatism, and the Transformation of Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981); Rudy Koshar, “Cult of Associations? The Lower Middle Classes in Weimar Germany,” in Rudy Koshar, ed., Splintered Classes (New York: Holmes and Meier, 1990); and Hagtvet (fn. 12).
38. Larry Eugene Jones, German Liberalism and the Dissolution of the Weimar Party System, 1918-1933 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1988).
39. Fritzsche (fn. 36), chap. 2, quote at 21. On the middle classes and the revolution, see also Arthur Rosenberg, A History of the German Republic (London: Methuen, 1936); Winkler and Kocka (fn. 26).
40. Fritzsche (fn. 36), 76.
41. The most comprehensive treatment of almost all aspects of the Great Inflation and its aftermath is Gerald Feldman, The Great Disorder: Politics, Economics and Society in the German Inflation, 1919-1924 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993). On the psychological aspects in particular, see Jürgen von Krüdener, “Die Entstehung des Inflationstraumas: Zur Sozialpsychologie der deutschen Hyperinflation 1922-23,” in Gerald Feldman et al., eds. Consequences of Inflation (Berlin: Colloquium, 1989).
42. Larry Eugene Jones, “‘The Dying Middle’: Weimar Germany and the Fragmentation of Bourgeois Politics,” Central European History 5 (1972), 25; see also Kocka (fn. 37).
43. The spd itself did much to preserve its image as a worker’s rather than a people’s party. See Richard Hunt, German Social Democracy, 1918-1933 (Chicago: Quadrangle Books, 1964); Donna Harsch, German Social Democracy and the Rise of Fascism (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1993); Heinrich August Winkler, “Klassenbewegung oder Volkspartei?” Geschichte und Gesellschaft, vol. 8, 1972; Hans Kremdahl, “Könnte die spd der Weimarer Republik eine Volkspartei werden?” in Horst Heimann and Thomas Meyer, eds., Reformsozialismus und Sozialdemokratie (Berlin: Verlag J.H.W. Dietz, 1982); and Sheri Berman, Ideas and Politics: Social Democracy in Interwar Europe (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, forthcoming).
44. The 1920s even saw something of a resuscitation of the old Bismarckian coalition of iron and rye, which like its predecessor was able to secure a wide range of subsidies and tariffs, the most infamous of which was the Osthilfe. See Dietmar Petzina, “Elemente der Wirtschaftspolitik in der Spätphase der Weimarer Republik, Vierteljahrshefte für Zeitgeschichte 21 (1973); and Gerald Feldman, Vom Weltkrieg zur Weltwirtschaftskrise (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1984).
45. Jones (fnn. 38, 42); idem, “In the Shadow of Stabilization: German Liberalism and the Legitimacy of the Weimar Party System,” and Thomas Childers, “Interest and Ideology: Anti-System Parties in the Era of Stabilization,” both in Gerald Feldman, ed., Die Nachwirkungen der Inflation auf die deutsche Geschichte (Munich: R. Oldenburg Verlag, 1985). See also Hans Mommsen, “The Decline of the Bürgertum in Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century Germany,” in Mommsen, From Weimar to Auschwitz (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1991).
46. Koshar (fn. 23), 166. See also Gerald Feldman, “German Interest Group Alliances in War and Inflation, 1914-1923,” in Berger (fn. 37); and Charles Maier, “Strukturen kapitalistischer Stabilität in den zwanziger Jahren,” in Winkler (fn. 26).
47. Detlev J. K. Peukert, The Weimar Republic (New York: Hill and Wang, 1989), 230.
48. Fritzsche (fn. 36), 76.
49. Among the other goals of this neo-Tocquevillean paragon, it is interesting to note, were rearmament, the extirpation of degeneration and foreign influence, and the acquisition of Lebensraum. “Berlin Stahlhelm Manifesto,” first published in Stahlhelm und Staat (May 8, 1927), reprinted in Anton Kaes, Martin Jay, and Edward Dimendberg, eds., The Weimar Republic Sourcebook (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1994), 339-40. On the development of the Stahlhelm, see Fritzsche (fn. 36), chap. 9; Volker Berghahn, Der Stahlhelm: Bund der Frontsoldaten, 1918-1935 (Düsseldorf: Droste, 1966); and J. M. Diehl, Paramilitary Politics in Weimar Germany (Bloomington: University of Indiana Press, 1977).
50. A good summary of the history of the Nazi party during this time is provided by Dietrich Orlow, The History of the Nazi Party, 1919-1933 (Pittsburgh, Pa.: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1969). Good English-language treatments of the formation of the Nazi constituency include Thomas Childers, ed., The Formation of the Nazi Constituency (London: Croom Helm, 1986); idem, “The Middle Classes and National Socialism,” in Blackbourn and Evans (fn. 25); Peter Stachura, ed., The Nazi Machtergreifung (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1983);
and Thomas Childers, The Nazi Voter: The Social Foundations of Fascism in Germany (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1983). Perhaps the most up-to-date analysis in German is Jürgen W. Falter, Hitlers Wähler (Munich: Verlag C.H. Beck,1991).
51. Fritzsche (fn. 36), 13.
52. Rudy Koshar, “From Stammtisch to Party: Nazi Joiners and the Contradictions of Grass Roots Fascism in Weimar Germany,” Journal of Modern History 59 (March 1987), 2; idem (fn. 23), 185ff.; Hans Mommsen, “National Socialism: Continuity and Change,” in Walter Lacquer, ed., Fascism: A Reader’s Guide (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1976); and Hagtvet (fn. 12).
53. Koshar, “Contentious Citadel: Bourgeois Crisis and Nazism in Marburg/Lahn, 1880-1933,” in Childers (fn. 50), 24, 28-29. See also Koshar (fn. 23); Hagtvet (fn. 12); Allen (fn. 36); and idem, “The Nazification of a Town,” in John L. Snell, ed., The Nazi Revolution: Hitler’s Dictatorship and the German Nation (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1973).
54. In a study of right-wing extremists in the U.S., Raymond Wolfinger and several colleagues came to a similar conclusion. See Wolfinger et al., “America’s Radical Right: Politics and Ideology,” in David E. Apter, ed., Ideology and Discontent (New York: Free Press, 1964).
55. Koshar (fn. 23), 202.
56. Ibid., 204, 202.
57. On the party’s infiltration of a variety of bourgeois associations, see Mommsen (fn. 52); Winkler (fn. 26), 168ff.; Larry Eugene Jones, “Between the Fronts: The German National Union of Commercial Employees from 1928 to 1933,” Journal of Modern History 48 (September 1976); Koshar (fn. 37); and Peter D. Stachura, “German Youth, the Youth Movement and National Socialism in the Weimar Republic,” in Stachura, ed., The Nazi Machtergreifung (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1983).
58. In the 1928 elections, for example, the NSDAP share of the vote in the predominently rural districts of East Prussia, Pomerania, East Hannover, and Hesse-Darmstadt was below its national average. Horst Gies, “The NSDAP and Agrarian Organizations in the Final Phase of the Weimar Republic,” in Henry A. Turner, ed., Nazism and the Third Reich (New York: New Viewpoints, 1972), 75 fn. 2. See also Richard J. Evans and W. R. Lee, eds., The German Peasantry (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1986); Robert G. Moeller, German Peasants and Agrarian Politics, 1914-1924 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1986); Shelley Baranowski, The Sanctity of Rural Life: Nobility, Protestantism, and Nazism in West Prussia (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995); and Werner Angress, “The Political Role of the Peasantry,” Review of Politics 21, no. 3 (1959).
59. On Nazi agricultural policy during this period, see J. E. Farquharson, The Plough and the Swastika: The NSDAP and Agriculture in Germany, 1928-1945 (London: Sage, 1976). For a discussion of why other parties such as the spd passed up this opportunity, see Berman (fn. 43).
60. Quoted in Gies (fn. 58), 51.
61. Ibid., 62. See also Zdenek Zofka, “Between Bauernbund and National Socialism: The Political Orientation of the Peasantry in the Final Phase of the Weimar Republic,” in Childers (fn. 50).
62. Ibid., 65.
63. Hagtvet (fn. 12), 91.
64. At least partially because of the rlb’s efforts, which were directed by the Nazis; Hagtvet (fn. 12), 75.
65. In a tragic irony, Hindenburg’s decision may well have allowed the Nazis to snatch victory from the jaws of defeat. After the July 1932 elections the NSDAP began to run into trouble, as Hitler’s inability to deliver on his promises caused dissent among different groups within the Nazi coalition and the party’s previously formidable organization had trouble maintaining necessary levels of enthusiasm and funding. A few months more out of power and the party might have begun to self-destruct. See the new study by Henry Ashby Turner, Jr., Hitler’s Thirty Days to Power: January 1933 (New York: Addison-Wesley, 1996); and also Orlow (fn. 50), 233ff.; and Childers, “The Limits of National Socialist Mobilization,” in Childers (fn. 50).
66. Many, indeed, have blamed Bismarck for the nature of the German party system. By allowing universal suffrage but failing to provide responsible government, Bismarck ensured that political parties would be necessary but also somewhat impotent. Furthermore, by continually manufacturing crises and identifying certain parties (i.e., the spd and Zentrum) as enemies of the Reich, Bismarck increased the difficulty that parties and their constituencies had in working with each other.
67. Both the spd and the Catholic Zentrum managed to avoid such problems with their core consituencies. Each maintained close ties with an extremely wide range of ancilliary organizations, and the spd in particular was a very effective mass party. Largely as a result of these parties’ ability to integrate political and civil society life, their constituencies (i.e., workers and Catholics) proved less likely to vote for the Nazis later on than were other groups. Because they contributed to the segmentation of German society during the 1920s, however, these parties can still be held at least indirectly responsible for the collapse of the Weimar Republic.
68. Fritzsche (fn. 36), 232. On this point, see also M. Rainer Lepsius, “Parteiensystem und Sozialstruktur: zum Problem der Demokratisierung der deutschen Gesellschaft,” in Gerhard A. Ritter, ed., Deutsche Parteien vor 1918 (Cologne: Droste, 1983).
69. Foley and Edwards (fn. 7); Skocpol (fn. 7, “The Tocqueville Problem”); Diamond (fn. 7); Pinard (fn. 19); Hagtvet (fn. 12), esp. 94; Koshar (fnn. 37, 23); Winkler (fn. 26), esp. 196; and Fritzsche (fn. 36).
70. See Sidney Tarrow, “Making Social Science Work across Space and Time: A Critical Reflection on Robert Putnam’s Making Democracy Work,” American Political Science Review 90 (June 1996). Interestingly, Tarrow also criticizes Putnam for failing to recognize that much of the civil society activity he finds was directly or indirectly created by Italian political parties. According to Tarrow, in other words, civil society may not be an independent variable (as Putnam claims) but rather an intermediary variable, along the lines suggested by the analysis presented here.
71. Ward 3 block-watch organizer Kathy Smith and Cleveland Park Citizens Association president Stephen A. Koczak, respectively, quoted in Francis X Clines, “Washington’s Troubles Hit Island of Affluence,” New York Times, July 26, 1996, p. A19.
72. “Promoting a Return to ‘Civil Society,’ Diverse Group of Crusaders Looks to New Solutions to Social Problems,” Washington Post, December 15, 1996.
73. On this point, see also Skocpol (fn. 7, 1996, 1996).
"Looking for a Similar Assignment? Get Expert Help at an Amazing Discount!"
